Divergence: the balance sheets edition

This article is an on-site version of our Chris Giles on Central Banks newsletter. Premium subscribers can sign up here to get the newsletter delivered every Tuesday. Standard subscribers can upgrade to Premium here, or explore all FT newsletters

The overarching theme of central banks’ policy paths in 2025 seems to be divergence. The Federal Reserve is set to keep interest rates high, while the European Central Bank will leave restriction behind and possibly even move to an accommodative stance. The Bank of England is somewhere in between, while the Bank of Japan will probably raise rates again.

But it’s not just on rate decisions that central banks are dividing. Quantitative tightening is still under way, but the question of what central bank balance sheets should look like in the long run is now live — and, for the first time in recent history, each institution has its own answer.

What are the options — and what are the risks?

Option 1: ample supply of liquidity

The first option is for central banks to keep their balance sheet permanently large, continuing to supply liquidity to the financial system in excess of what it requires through an extensive bond portfolio.

This system, known as ample reserves, was adopted by the Fed, ECB and BoE in the wake of the global financial crisis and has been in vogue since.

In this framework, the interest rate that banks charge to lend reserves in the overnight interbank market is very close to the rate that they would obtain by depositing their excess reserves at the central bank. Because the latter is directly controlled by the central bank, this framework gives policymakers much tighter control on overnight rates — and therefore on financial conditions.

There is, however, a major trade-off: a permanently large balance sheet is unwieldy, constraining the central bank’s ability to ramp up asset purchases in future crises. Moreover, a large balance sheet is expensive for public finances when the yield on assets on the balance sheet (which pay interest to the central bank) is lower than the short-term rate (which the central bank pays to commercial banks).

Of the large western central banks, it is only the Fed that intends to continue using this framework.

The Fed’s balance sheet peaked at $8.9tn, or 37 per cent of GDP, in early 2022. For the past few years, the liquidity it provided to the financial system has been well in excess of the level required for it to function. In effect, this means the Fed has been operating an abundant, not simply ample, reserves regime.

Through QT, which started later in 2022, policymakers aim to reduce the size of the balance sheet to the minimum consistent with the ample reserves framework.

How far away is the Fed from that sweet spot — and what could go wrong?

In the third quarter of 2024, the Fed’s reserves amounted to $3.1tn, or about 11 per cent of GDP. Fed board of governors member Christopher Waller had previously estimated that reserves would have to fall to 10-11 per cent of GDP before officials would consider terminating QT.

When thinking about the risks of crossing the ample reserves threshold, officials will cast their minds to September 2019. Back then, the fateful combination of a corporate tax deadline and a bout of Treasury issuance tipped system-wide reserves briefly into scarcity, prompting a sharp spike in overnight lending rates and forcing the Fed to provide emergency liquidity.

In 2021, the Fed introduced a new tool to stave off the risk of a repeat. The standing repo facility allows banks to borrow temporary liquidity from the Fed in return for high-quality collateral. Yet the SRF is an emergency tool, not a regular source of liquidity provision.

With reserves now near the threshold, signs of money market stress are rising. In September, the Sofr rate (secured overnight financing rate) at which banks lend to each other overnight against Treasury collateral jumped briefly.

Fed officials were quick to shrug off the story. Yet, as my colleague Andrew Whiffin wrote, the rollout of a new reserves demand elasticity tracker suggests that policymakers may be more concerned than they are letting on.

Donald Trump’s economic agenda is set to muddy the picture further still. The president-elect’s promised tax cuts will be partly bankrolled by deficit spending, which would raise Treasury issuance and drain liquidity. Moreover, if inflationary pressures build up again, the Fed will have to adopt a tighter policy stance. In this environment, emergency injections of liquidity to counteract any instability in the money markets would come with the risk of interfering with rate-setters’ monetary policy goals.

Option 2: scarce reserves

The second option would be for central banks to shrink their balance sheets below the point at which reserves are ample.

In one version of this system, which was widely used before the financial crisis, a central bank provided just enough liquidity to broadly satisfy demand from the financial system, but no more.

To stop-gap any shortfall or absorb surplus liquidity, central banks offered borrowing and lending facilities with interest rates in a band around the policy rate. Banks could deposit surplus reserves at the central bank at a rate slightly below the target rate, or borrow additional liquidity from it at a slightly higher rate. This meant the overnight rate at which institutions borrowed from each other was most often somewhere in between the “corridor” set up by the central bank.

But to calibrate the corridor effectively, central banks needed a reasonably good idea of the financial system’s demand for liquidity — and to be ready for constant adjustment. This has got harder: most policymakers believe demand for liquidity is now structurally higher and less stable than in the past.

This system is still nominally in place at the ECB, which in September narrowed the spread of its rates corridor. In effect, however, because liquidity in the Eurosystem is still in excess, the overnight interest rate has long been anchored around the ECB’s deposit rate.

Option 3: ample reserves and liquidity on demand

The third option was last year outlined by BoE governor Andrew Bailey. Under it, the central bank would commit to providing ample reserves, but only partially through a permanent bond portfolio, in contrast to the Fed’s plans.

Instead, the BoE would make available a portion of reserves on demand by offering unlimited collateral-backed repurchase agreements to financial institutions at the policy rate. This would enable policymakers to keep tight control over the overnight lending rate, while reaping the benefits of a smaller balance sheet that could scale up substantially in times of crisis.

In this framework, the central bank could scale back its bond holdings below the ample-reserves threshold. However, unlike in the pre-crisis scarce reserves framework, it would not have to actively determine the right amount of liquidity for the whole system, since financial institutions would have the ability to turn to the central bank for unlimited “top-ups” as necessary.

Part of the BoE’s eagerness to run a permanently smaller balance sheet is because in the UK, central bank losses are crystallised as fiscal costs and not deferred as in other jurisdictions. This means that since the start of QT, the Old Lady has dragged on the Treasury. Understandably, policymakers are keen to find a system that works better for the taxpayer.

But it is also plausible that freeing up the option to conduct large-scale asset purchases in a crisis is more appealing for countries whose sovereign asset is not a safe haven. This is a problem the Fed does not have.

The ECB has given only general indications of its long-term balance sheet plans: a full announcement is expected in 2026. Yet all the signs suggest that the governing council would also like a liquidity-on-demand system like the BoE’s proposal.

But there are some constraints on the ECB’s ambitions. Most notably, its outsize bond portfolio has played a bigger role than just liquidity provision. ECB bond purchases have also helped to keep core and peripheral sovereign yields anchored to each other, countering fragmentation — a longtime bugbear of Eurozone policymakers.

The question is how the ECB could continue to play that role under a balance-sheet framework with a much-reduced bond portfolio. It is probably an unspoken reason why the governing council sees at least some role for “a structural portfolio of securities [to be] introduced at a later stage”.

The most ambitious fix is out of the central bank’s hands. Progress towards fiscal mutualisation in Brussels would reduce the ECB’s (largely uncredited) role in countering fragmentation through its balance sheet. Yet the governing council would be wise to not count on progress on this already long-delayed front in time for 2026.

What I’ve been reading and watching

  • The crypto industry wants Donald Trump to make bitcoin just mainstream enough to broaden its adoption across the financial system — but not mainstream enough to catch the regulator’s eye. What could possibly go wrong?

  • Richmond Fed president Tom Barkin is worried about inflation in 2025

  • Norma Percy’s magnificent Watergate documentary, first broadcast in 1994, is a gripping watch in a year in which political drama in Washington is all but guaranteed

Free lunch — Your guide to the global economic policy debate. Sign up here

The Lex Newsletter — Lex, our investment column, breaks down the week’s key themes, with analysis by award-winning writers. Sign up here


Source link

Total
0
Shares
Related Posts